Solved

Macroeconomists Who Study the Determinants of Per Capita Income (The

Question 22

Essay

Macroeconomists who study the determinants of per capita income (the "wealth of nations")have been particularly interested in finding evidence on conditional convergence in the countries of the world. Finding such a result would imply that all countries would end up with the same per capita income once other variables such as saving and population growth rates, education, government policies, etc., took on the same value. Unconditional convergence, on the other hand, does not control for these additional variables.
(a)The results of the regression for 104 countries was as follows, g6090^=0.0190.0006× RelProd 60,R2=0.00007,SER=0.016(0.004)(0.0073),\begin{aligned}\widehat { g 6090 } = & 0.019 - 0.0006 \times \text { RelProd } _ { 60 } , R 2 = 0.00007 , S E R = 0.016 \\& ( 0.004 ) ( 0.0073 ) ,\end{aligned}
where g6090 is the average annual growth rate of GDP per worker for the 1960-1990 sample period, and RelProd60 is GDP per worker relative to the United States in 1960.
For the 24 OECD countries in the sample, the output is g6090^\widehat { g 6090 } = 0.048 - 0.0404 RelProd60, R2 = 0.82, SER = 0.0046
(0.004)(0.0063)
Interpret the results and point out the difference with regard to unconditional convergence.
(b)The "beta-convergence" regressions in (a)are of the following type, ΔtlnYi,tT\frac { \Delta _ { t } \ln Y _ { i , t } } { T } = ?0 + ?0 ln Yi,0 + ui,t,
where ?t ln Yi,t = ln Yi,0 - ln Yi,0, and t and o refer to two time periods, i is the i-th country.
Explain why a significantly negative slope implies convergence (hence the name).
(c)The equation in (b)can be rewritten without any change in information as (ignoring the division by T)
ln Yt = ?0 + ?1 ln Y0 + ut
In this form, how would you test for unconditional convergence? What would be the implication for convergence if the slope coefficient were one?
(d)Let's write the equation in (c)as follows: Y~t=β0+γ1Y~0+ut\tilde { Y } _ { t = \beta _ { 0 } + \gamma _ { 1 } } \tilde { Y } _ { 0 } + u _ { t } and assume that the "~" variables contain measurement errors of the following type, Yi,t~=Yt+vi,t and Yi,0~=Y0+wi,0\tilde { Y _ { i , t } } =Y _ { t }^* + v _ { i , t } \text { and } \tilde { Y _ { i , 0 } } = Y _ { 0 } ^ { * } + w _ { i , 0 } \text {. } where the "*" variables represent true, or permanent, per capita income components, while v and w are temporary or transitory components. Subtraction of the initial period from the current period then results in Yi,t~=(YtY0)+Yi,0~+(vi,twi,0)\tilde { Y _ { i , t } } = \left( Y _ { t } ^ { * } - Y _ { 0 }^ { * } \right) + \tilde { Y _ { i , 0 } } + \left( v _ { i , t } - w _ { i , 0 } \right) Ignoring, without loss of generality, the constant in the above equation, and making standard assumptions about the error term, one can show that by regressing current per capita income on a constant and the initial period per capita income, the slope behaves as follows: β^1p1σv2σy2+σv2\hat { \beta } _ { 1 } \xrightarrow{p} 1 - \frac { \sigma _ { v } ^ { 2 } } { \sigma _ { y } ^ { 2^* } + \sigma _ { v } ^ { 2 } } Discuss the implications for the convergence results above.

Correct Answer:

verifed

Verified

(a)There is evidence for unconditional c...

View Answer

Unlock this answer now
Get Access to more Verified Answers free of charge

Related Questions