Exam 28: A: Game Applications
Exam 1: Budget Constraint58 Questions
Exam 1: A: Budget Constraint30 Questions
Exam 2: Preferences49 Questions
Exam 2: A: Preferences30 Questions
Exam 3: Utility57 Questions
Exam 3: A: Utility29 Questions
Exam 4: Choice63 Questions
Exam 4: A: Choice31 Questions
Exam 5: Demand79 Questions
Exam 5: A: Demand22 Questions
Exam 6: Revealed Preference58 Questions
Exam 6: A: Revealed Preference26 Questions
Exam 7: Slutsky Equation51 Questions
Exam 7: A: Slutsky Equation30 Questions
Exam 8: Buying and Selling75 Questions
Exam 8: A: Buying and Selling30 Questions
Exam 9: Intertemporal Choice61 Questions
Exam 9: A: Intertemporal Choice30 Questions
Exam 10: Asset Markets46 Questions
Exam 10: A: Asset Markets30 Questions
Exam 11: Uncertainty39 Questions
Exam 11: A: Uncertainty25 Questions
Exam 12: Risky Assets16 Questions
Exam 12: A: Risky Assets10 Questions
Exam 13: Consumers Surplus42 Questions
Exam 13: A: Consumers Surplus30 Questions
Exam 14: Market Demand101 Questions
Exam 14: A: Market Demand25 Questions
Exam 15: Equilibrium48 Questions
Exam 15: A: Equilibrium20 Questions
Exam 16: Auctions36 Questions
Exam 16: A: Auctions25 Questions
Exam 17: Technology52 Questions
Exam 17: A: Technology30 Questions
Exam 18: Profit Maximization52 Questions
Exam 18: A: Profit Maximization21 Questions
Exam 19: Cost Minimization77 Questions
Exam 19: A: Cost Minimization26 Questions
Exam 20: Cost Curves51 Questions
Exam 20: A: Cost Curves20 Questions
Exam 21: Firm Supply41 Questions
Exam 21: A: Firm Supply15 Questions
Exam 22: Industry Supply49 Questions
Exam 22: A: Industry Supply33 Questions
Exam 23: Monopoly76 Questions
Exam 23: A: Monopoly30 Questions
Exam 24: Monopoly Behavior34 Questions
Exam 24: A: Monopoly Behavior20 Questions
Exam 25: Factor Markets24 Questions
Exam 25: A: Factor Markets20 Questions
Exam 26: Oligopoly56 Questions
Exam 26: A: Oligopoly30 Questions
Exam 27: Game Theory34 Questions
Exam 27: A: Game Theory25 Questions
Exam 28: Game Applications28 Questions
Exam 28: A: Game Applications25 Questions
Exam 29: Behavioral Economics34 Questions
Exam 30: Exchange68 Questions
Exam 30: A: Exchange30 Questions
Exam 31: Production35 Questions
Exam 31: A: Production25 Questions
Exam 32: Welfare27 Questions
Exam 32: A: Welfare25 Questions
Exam 33: Externalities42 Questions
Exam 33: A: Externalities25 Questions
Exam 34: Information Technology24 Questions
Exam 34: A: Information Technology15 Questions
Exam 35: Public Goods26 Questions
Exam 35: A: Public Goods20 Questions
Exam 36: Asymmetric Information31 Questions
Exam 36: A: Asymmetric Information20 Questions
Select questions type
Suppose that in the Hawk-Dove game discussed in Problem 8, the payoff to each player is -7 if both play Hawk. If both play Dove, the payoff to each player is 4, and if one plays Hawk and the other plays Dove, the one that plays Hawk gets a payoff of 7 and the one that plays Dove gets 0. In equilibrium, we would expect hawks and doves to do equally well. This happens when the proportion of the total population that plays Hawk is
Free
(Multiple Choice)
4.9/5
(43)
Correct Answer:
B
(See Problem 3.) Two players are engaged in a game of "chicken." There are two possible strategies, Swerve and Drive Straight. A player who chooses to Swerve is called "chicken" and gets a payoff of zero, regardless of what the other player does. A player who chooses to Drive Straight gets a payoff of 3 if the other player Swerves and a payoff of -12 if the other player also chooses to Drive Straight. This game has two pure strategy equilibria and
Free
(Multiple Choice)
4.9/5
(31)
Correct Answer:
A
(See Problem 2.) Arthur and Bertha are asked by their boss to vote on a company policy. Each of them will be allowed to vote for one of three possible policies, A, B, and C. Arthur likes A best, B second best, and C least. Bertha likes B best, A second best, and C least. The money value to Arthur of outcome C is $0, outcome B is $1, and outcome A is $3. The money value to Bertha of outcome C is $0, outcome B is $4, and outcome A is $1. The boss likes outcome C best, but if Arthur and Bertha both vote for one of the other outcomes, he will pick the outcome they voted for. If Arthur and Bertha vote for different outcomes, the boss will pick C. Arthur and Bertha know this is the case. They are not allowed to communicate with each other, and each decides to use a mixed strategy in which each randomizes between voting for A or for B. What is the mixed strategy equilibrium for Arthur and Bertha in this game?
Free
(Multiple Choice)
4.9/5
(32)
Correct Answer:
C
(See Problem 3.) Two players are engaged in a game of "chicken." There are two possible strategies, Swerve and Drive Straight. A player who chooses to Swerve is called "chicken" and gets a payoff of zero, regardless of what the other player does. A player who chooses to Drive Straight gets a payoff of 4 if the other player Swerves and a payoff of -36 if the other player also chooses to Drive Straight. This game has two pure strategy equilibria and
(Multiple Choice)
4.8/5
(34)
(See Problem 6.) Big Pig and Little Pig have two possible strategies, Press the Button, and Wait at the Trough. If both pigs choose Wait, both get 3. If both pigs Press the Button, then Big Pig gets 9 and Little Pig gets 1. If Little Pig Presses the Button and Big Pig Waits at the Trough, then Big Pig gets 10 and Little Pig gets 0. Finally, if Big Pig Presses the Button and Little Pig Waits, then Big Pig gets 4 and Little Pig gets 1. In Nash equilibrium,
(Multiple Choice)
4.9/5
(37)
(See Problem 7.) The old Michigan football coach had only two strategies, Run the Ball to the Left Side of the line, and Run the Ball to the Right Side. The defense can concentrate either on the left side or the right side of Michigan's line. If the opponent concentrates on the wrong side, Michigan is sure to gain at least 5 yards. If the defense defended the left side and Michigan ran left, Michigan would be stopped for no gain. But if the opponent defended the right side when Michigan ran right, Michigan would still gain at least 5 yards with probability .70. It is the last play of the game and Michigan needs to gain 5 yards to win. Both sides choose Nash equilibrium strategies. In Nash equilibrium, Michigan would
(Multiple Choice)
4.8/5
(33)
Suppose that in the Hawk-Dove game discussed in Problem 8, the payoff to each player is -3 if both play Hawk. If both play Dove, the payoff to each player is 1, and if one plays Hawk and the other plays Dove, the one that plays Hawk gets a payoff of 5 and the one that plays Dove gets 0. In equilibrium, we would expect hawks and doves to do equally well. This happens when the proportion of the total population that plays Hawk is
(Multiple Choice)
4.9/5
(40)
(See Problem 7.) The old Michigan football coach had only two strategies, Run the Ball to the Left Side of the line, and Run the Ball to the Right Side. The defense can concentrate either on the left side or the right side of Michigan's line. If the opponent concentrates on the wrong side, Michigan is sure to gain at least 5 yards. If the defense defended the left side and Michigan ran left, Michigan would be stopped for no gain. But if the opponent defended the right side when Michigan ran right, Michigan would still gain at least 5 yards with probability .60. It is the last play of the game and Michigan needs to gain 5 yards to win. Both sides choose Nash equilibrium strategies. In Nash equilibrium, Michigan would
(Multiple Choice)
4.8/5
(35)
(See Problem 7.) The old Michigan football coach had only two strategies, Run the Ball to the Left Side of the line, and Run the Ball to the Right Side. The defense can concentrate either on the left side or the right side of Michigan's line. If the opponent concentrates on the wrong side, Michigan is sure to gain at least 5 yards. If the defense defended the left side and Michigan ran left, Michigan would be stopped for no gain. But if the opponent defended the right side when Michigan ran right, Michigan would still gain at least 5 yards with probability .70. It is the last play of the game and Michigan needs to gain 5 yards to win. Both sides choose Nash equilibrium strategies. In Nash equilibrium, Michigan would
(Multiple Choice)
4.9/5
(33)
(See Problem 6.) Big Pig and Little Pig have two possible strategies, Press the Button, and Wait at the Trough. If both pigs choose Wait, both get 1. If both pigs Press the Button, then Big Pig gets 9 and Little Pig gets 1. If Little Pig Presses the Button and Big Pig Waits at the Trough, then Big Pig gets 10 and Little Pig gets 0. Finally, if Big Pig Presses the Button and Little Pig Waits, then Big Pig gets 5 and Little Pig gets 1. In Nash equilibrium,
(Multiple Choice)
4.8/5
(35)
(See Problem 7.) The old Michigan football coach had only two strategies, Run the Ball to the Left Side of the line, and Run the Ball to the Right Side. The defense can concentrate either on the left side or the right side of Michigan's line. If the opponent concentrates on the wrong side, Michigan is sure to gain at least 5 yards. If the defense defended the left side and Michigan ran left, Michigan would be stopped for no gain. But if the opponent defended the right side when Michigan ran right, Michigan would still gain at least 5 yards with probability .70. It is the last play of the game and Michigan needs to gain 5 yards to win. Both sides choose Nash equilibrium strategies. In Nash equilibrium, Michigan would
(Multiple Choice)
4.8/5
(36)
(See Problem 3.) Two players are engaged in a game of "chicken." There are two possible strategies, Swerve and Drive Straight. A player who chooses to Swerve is called "chicken" and gets a payoff of zero, regardless of what the other player does. A player who chooses to Drive Straight gets a payoff of 84 if the other player Swerves and a payoff of -36 if the other player also chooses to Drive Straight. This game has two pure strategy equilibria and
(Multiple Choice)
4.9/5
(46)
(See Problem 2.) Arthur and Bertha are asked by their boss to vote on a company policy. Each of them will be allowed to vote for one of three possible policies, A, B, and C. Arthur likes A best, B second best, and C least. Bertha likes B best, A second best, and C least. The money value to Arthur of outcome C is $0, outcome B is $1, and outcome A is $5. The money value to Bertha of outcome C is $0, outcome B is $4, and outcome A is $1. The boss likes outcome C best, but if Arthur and Bertha both vote for one of the other outcomes, he will pick the outcome they voted for. If Arthur and Bertha vote for different outcomes, the boss will pick C. Arthur and Bertha know this is the case. They are not allowed to communicate with each other, and each decides to use a mixed strategy in which each randomizes between voting for A or for B. What is the mixed strategy equilibrium for Arthur and Bertha in this game?
(Multiple Choice)
4.7/5
(39)
(See Problem 7.) The old Michigan football coach had only two strategies, Run the Ball to the Left Side of the line, and Run the Ball to the Right Side. The defense can concentrate either on the left side or the right side of Michigan's line. If the opponent concentrates on the wrong side, Michigan is sure to gain at least 5 yards. If the defense defended the left side and Michigan ran left, Michigan would be stopped for no gain. But if the opponent defended the right side when Michigan ran right, Michigan would still gain at least 5 yards with probability .50. It is the last play of the game and Michigan needs to gain 5 yards to win. Both sides choose Nash equilibrium strategies. In Nash equilibrium, Michigan would
(Multiple Choice)
4.7/5
(36)
Suppose that in the Hawk-Dove game discussed in Problem 8, the payoff to each player is -7 if both play Hawk. If both play Dove, the payoff to each player is 5, and if one plays Hawk and the other plays Dove, the one that plays Hawk gets a payoff of 9 and the one that plays Dove gets 0. In equilibrium, we would expect hawks and doves to do equally well. This happens when the proportion of the total population that plays Hawk is
(Multiple Choice)
4.7/5
(30)
(See Problem 6.) Big Pig and Little Pig have two possible strategies, Press the Button, and Wait at the Trough. If both pigs choose Wait, both get 1. If both pigs Press the Button, then Big Pig gets 6 and Little Pig gets 4. If Little Pig Presses the Button and Big Pig Waits at the Trough, then Big Pig gets 10 and Little Pig gets 0. Finally, if Big Pig Presses the Button and Little Pig Waits, then Big Pig gets 6 and Little Pig gets 2. In Nash equilibrium,
(Multiple Choice)
4.9/5
(35)
(See Problem 2.) Arthur and Bertha are asked by their boss to vote on a company policy. Each of them will be allowed to vote for one of three possible policies, A, B, and C. Arthur likes A best, B second best, and C least. Bertha likes B best, A second best, and C least. The money value to Arthur of outcome C is $0, outcome B is $1, and outcome A is $4. The money value to Bertha of outcome C is $0, outcome B is $4, and outcome A is $1. The boss likes outcome C best, but if Arthur and Bertha both vote for one of the other outcomes, he will pick the outcome they voted for. If Arthur and Bertha vote for different outcomes, the boss will pick C. Arthur and Bertha know this is the case. They are not allowed to communicate with each other, and each decides to use a mixed strategy in which each randomizes between voting for A or for B. What is the mixed strategy equilibrium for Arthur and Bertha in this game?
(Multiple Choice)
4.8/5
(41)
(See Problem 3.) Two players are engaged in a game of "chicken." There are two possible strategies, Swerve and Drive Straight. A player who chooses to Swerve is called "chicken" and gets a payoff of zero, regardless of what the other player does. A player who chooses to Drive Straight gets a payoff of 15.43 if the other player Swerves and a payoff of -36 if the other player also chooses to Drive Straight. This game has two pure strategy equilibria and
(Multiple Choice)
5.0/5
(36)
(See Problem 2.) Arthur and Bertha are asked by their boss to vote on a company policy. Each of them will be allowed to vote for one of three possible policies, A, B, and C. Arthur likes A best, B second best, and C least. Bertha likes B best, A second best, and C least. The money value to Arthur of outcome C is $0, outcome B is $1, and outcome A is $3. The money value to Bertha of outcome C is $0, outcome B is $4, and outcome A is $1. The boss likes outcome C best, but if Arthur and Bertha both vote for one of the other outcomes, he will pick the outcome they voted for. If Arthur and Bertha vote for different outcomes, the boss will pick C. Arthur and Bertha know this is the case. They are not allowed to communicate with each other, and each decides to use a mixed strategy in which each randomizes between voting for A or for B. What is the mixed strategy equilibrium for Arthur and Bertha in this game?
(Multiple Choice)
4.8/5
(30)
(See Problem 2.) Arthur and Bertha are asked by their boss to vote on a company policy. Each of them will be allowed to vote for one of three possible policies, A, B, and C. Arthur likes A best, B second best, and C least. Bertha likes B best, A second best, and C least. The money value to Arthur of outcome C is $0, outcome B is $1, and outcome A is $4. The money value to Bertha of outcome C is $0, outcome B is $4, and outcome A is $1. The boss likes outcome C best, but if Arthur and Bertha both vote for one of the other outcomes, he will pick the outcome they voted for. If Arthur and Bertha vote for different outcomes, the boss will pick C. Arthur and Bertha know this is the case. They are not allowed to communicate with each other, and each decides to use a mixed strategy in which each randomizes between voting for A or for B. What is the mixed strategy equilibrium for Arthur and Bertha in this game?
(Multiple Choice)
4.8/5
(33)
Showing 1 - 20 of 25
Filters
- Essay(0)
- Multiple Choice(0)
- Short Answer(0)
- True False(0)
- Matching(0)